Interests VS Ideas – Building on Hobbes
Though not as stylishly pedantic
about their definitions as Hobbes; Laffey, Weldes, Goldstein, and Keohane bring
to the fore an important question. In what way do personal ideas shape politics
and policy?
To
address that question, they attempt to explain the reasoning behind their
concept of ‘ideas’. Goldstein and Keohane focus more directly on interests
versus ideas. They conceptualize ideas as a personally held conviction that may
or may not drive interests. By that standard, an idea is more of an ideal,
particularly as applied to politicians. The politician may have their own
ideals, but those do not always correspond directly with their expressed
interests. Particularly in today’s age of lobbyists and practical
considerations like re-elections. Which so often depend on lobbyists.
Laffey
and Weldes take a slightly different approach, exploring the concept of communal
ideas. This was an appealing theory, as it allows for the human tendency to
build upon the ideas of those who came before us. For instance, many modern
social science theorists whose work contains trace influences from Hobbes and
the many other writers who came before them. In particular, Laffey and Weldes’
structure with ideas stylized as ‘symbolic technologies’ or ‘commodities’, was especially
reminiscent of the current US patent system which very literally counts ideas as
objects and allows for the application of monetary value to those ideas.
Both
papers go on to suggest experiments designed to test the truth behind their
theories. As I have written previously, it is notoriously difficult to structure
unbiased social science experiments. An average lab setting isn’t possible because
you can’t pull a bunch of college students in for five dollars and expect them
to realistically re-create situations similar to those found in the world of
international policy. For one, they lack the experience of power and the heavy
weight of responsibility. Secondly, they come laden with their own biases based
upon their social and political beliefs.
Beliefs,
of course, are part of the core definition of an idea, bringing us back around
full circle to where we began, attempting to construct an unbiased experiment
to test the effect of ideas. There is also the option to take a longer view of
this problem, as Weber does when examining the compounding of ideas that led to
western society as we know it. Perhaps history truly is our greatest teacher.
Though Weber’s seemingly firm convictions in western societies superiority over
all others does leave the reader feeling faintly sticky.
Sources
Weber, Max. The Protestant Ethic
and Spirit of Capitalism. Boston University. Fitzroy Dearborn
Publishers. Chicago, IL. 2001.
Laffey, Mark; Weldes, Jutta. Beyond
Belief: Ideas and Symbolic Technologies in the Study of international
Relations. European Journal of International Relations. 1997.
Goldstein, Judith; Keohane, Robert
O. Ideas and Foreign Policy. Cornell University Press. 1993.
I am interested to know if you sympathized with Lakffey and Weldes's critique of Goldsteine and Keohane? Do you think ideas can so easily be typified as commodities as former accuse the latter?
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by the author.
DeleteI thought this was worth exploring in depth, so I wrote my post-class blog with this question in mind.
Delete